Russia Déjà Vu Soviet Union?

In the late 1980s, the Soviet Union was forced into an embarrassing scramble for money. It tried to make deals with numerous banks, but the funding offered was far smaller than what the country required. Food shortages worsened, and Moscow needed the help of governments in the West, for which the USSR effectively had to allow Eastern European countries to assert independence.

Writing in 2007, some warned against the consensus that oil prices would stay high:

What lessons can we learn from the Soviet collapse and apply to the current situation in Russia? First, we must remember that Russia today is an oil-dependent economy. No one can accurately predict the fluctuations of oil prices. The collapse of the Soviet Union should serve as a lesson to those who construct policy based on the assumption that oil prices will remain perpetually high. It would seem that in our country, which has lived through the collapse of the late 1980s and early 1990s, this fact would be evident. But as soon as the prices went up again at the beginning of 2000 and in 2004 became comparable in real terms to those at the beginning of the 1980s, the idea that “high oil revenues are forever” has gained an even wider acceptance.

Russia today isn’t the same top-down, command-and-control economy that it was in the 1980s, but the dynamic hasn’t changed entirely. The country is still hugely dependent on oil, particularly in terms of tax revenues and exports.

And Yego Gaida, the Russian economist, r thinks the collapse of the Soviet Union is still relevant for modern Russia:

One more lesson that is relevant for Russian politics today is that authoritarian regimes, although displaying a façade of strength, are fragile in crisis. In conditions of relative stability, society is prepared to tolerate the lack of real elections. People are prepared to come to terms with this situation as an inevitable and habitual evil. But they will do so only until the country encounters a serious challenge, requiring decisive and tough measures in order to adapt to unfavourable conditions.

Oil Prices and  Russia

When Robots Replace Jobs

Nouriel Roubini writes:  Technology innovators and CEOs seem positively giddy nowadays about what the future will bring. New manufacturing technologies have generated feverish excitement about what some see as a Third Industrial Revolution. In the years ahead, technological improvements in robotics and automation will boost productivity and efficiency, implying significant economic gains for companies. But, unless the proper policies to nurture job growth are put in place, it remains uncertain whether demand for labor will continue to grow as technology marches forward.

Recent technological advances have three biases: They tend to be capital-intensive (thus favoring those who already have financial resources); skill-intensive (thus favoring those who already have a high level of technical proficiency); and labor-saving (thus reducing the total number of unskilled and semi-skilled jobs in the economy). The risk is that robotics and automation will displace workers in blue-collar manufacturing jobs before the dust of the Third Industrial Revolution settles.

The rapid development of smart software over the last few decades has been perhaps the most important force shaping the coming manufacturing revolution. Software innovation, together with 3D printing technologies, will open the door to those workers who are educated enough to participate; for everyone else, however, it may feel as though the revolution is happening elsewhere.

For the developed countries, this may seem like old news. After all, for the last 30 years, the manufacturing base in Asia’s emerging economies has been displacing that of the old industrial powers of Western Europe and North America. But there is no guarantee that gains in service-sector employment will continue to offset the resulting job losses in industry.

Technology is making even many service jobs tradable.  Eventually echnology will replace manufacturing and service jobs in emerging markets as well.

Today, for example, a patient in New York may have his MRI sent digitally to, say, Bangalore, where a highly skilled radiologist reads it for one-quarter of what a New York-based radiologist would cost. But how long will it be before a computer software can read those images faster, better, and cheaper than the radiologist in Bangalore can?

Job-reducing technological innovations will affect education, health care, government, and even transportation.  Education and governments are shedding labor.  Even transportation is being revolutionized by technology. In a matter of years, driverless cars – courtesy of Google and others – may render millions of jobs obsolete.

And, of course technological innovation that is capital-intensive and labor-saving is one of the factors – together with the related winner-take-all effects – driving the rise in income and wealth inequality. Rising inequality then becomes a drag on demand and growth (as well as a source of social and political instability), because it distributes income from those who spend more (lower- and middle-income households) to those who save more (high-net-worth individuals and corporate firms).

Obviously, this is not the first time the world has faced such problems, and the past can help to serve as a model for resolving them. Late nineteenth- and early twentieth-century leaders sought to minimize the worst features of industrialization.

As we begin to seek enlightened solutions to the challenges that the Third Industrial Revolution presents, one overall theme looms large: The gains from technology must be channeled to a broader base of the population than has benefited so far. That requires a major educational component. In order to create broad-based prosperity, workers need the skills to participate in the brave new world implied by a digital economy.

Robots March Forward

 

 

Experiment with Policies?

J. Bradford de Long writes:  When it became clear in late 2008 that the global economy was headed toward a crash at least as dangerous as the one that had initiated the Great Depression, I was alarmed, but also hopeful. We had, after all, seen this before. And we also had a model for how to mitigate the damage; unfortunately, policymakers left it on the shelf.

Roosevelt’s New Deal policies sometimes conflicted with one another, and quite a few of them were counterproductive. But, by trying everything, and then scaling up the most successful policies, Roosevelt was ultimately able to turn the economy around.

And so, in late 2008, the way forward seemed obvious: recapitalize the banks, guarantee loans, use the government-backed housing lenders Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac to resolve underwater mortgages, drop short-term interest rates to zero and use quantitative easing to prevent deflation or dangerously low inflation, and embrace deficit spending. Then, as events evolved, we would reinforce those policies that seemed to be working and gradually drop those that seemed to be ineffective or counterproductive.

But that was not what we did. Instead, each proposal faced its own opposition. Some worried that recapitalizing the banks would reward the very institutions that had caused the problem. Others fretted that resolving underwater mortgages would reward feckless borrowers. Still others raised concerns about expansionary fiscal and monetary policy. And some favored one set of polices (say, resolving underwater mortgages and recapitalizing the banks), while opposing all the others (for example, deficit spending and raising inflation expectations).

Six years on, the economy has yet to fully recover and the problem persists. The usually wise economist Martin Feldstein makes the case for a set of policies designed to stimulate demand, including increasing investment tax credits and shifting the corporate-tax burden to firms that do not spend very much.

Feldstein’s ideas are promising; and, in line with the lessons of the Great Depression, they are definitely worth trying. The trouble is the rhetoric surrounding his proposals. The article’s headline, “The Fed’s Needless Flirtation With Danger,” is followed by warnings that quantitative easing could “increase the risk of financial instability.” Instead of simply promoting his policies, Feldstein presents them as a “safe and effective alternative” to other approaches. His proposals, he argues, are not an additional arrow in the quiver, but replacements for traditional Keynesian policies.

Pushing your ffavorite recipe at the expense of other is not productive. As policymakers continue to seek a path out of the ongoing malaise, it would be wise to remember Roosevelt’s words before he led the US out of a very similar crisis. “The country needs and…demands bold, persistent experimentation,” he said in 1932. “Take a method and try it. If it fails, admit it frankly, and try another. But above all, try something.”

Try Everything and the Kitchen Sink

Can Individual EU Nations Coordinate to Support the European Central Bank?

Jean Pisani Ferry writes: Eurozone monetary officials are expected to make history when they gather for the European Central Bank’s next policy-setting meeting on January 22.

The ECB has many reasons to launch QE.  Low inflation is already a serious obstacle to economic recovery and rebalancing within the eurozone. Outright deflation would be an even more dangerous threat.

Financial markets consider QE so likely that the largest part of its bond-rate and exchange-rate consequences have already been priced in. Should the ECB not launch QE,  markets would confront an abrupt and damaging unwinding of positions: long-term interest rates would rise, stock markets would sink, and the exchange rate would appreciate. That is not what Europe needs as it struggles.

Jens Weidmann, the president of the German Bundesbank argues that the consequences of recent price data may be less serious than believed, while those of full-fledged QE could be more serious than assumed.  At a time when the US data seem to validate the Federal Reserve’s strategy, why is the ECB hesitating?

The Bundesbank fiercely opposed the ECB’s conditional support of debt-distressed eurozone members, but German officials do not dispute the legitimacy of wholesale bond purchases for monetary-policy purposes.

In principle, QE has nothing to do with sovereign solvency. It is a monetary instrument that the central bank must rely on when its policy interest rate has hit the zero lower bound and thus cannot be pushed lower.

But, by lowering long-term interest rates, central-bank purchases of government debt can help contain government debt service. In this way, QE can keep solvent a government that otherwise would be insolvent.

Japan is a case in point. The Bank of Japan already holds government securities worth 40% of GDP, and it is committed to annual purchases worth 16% of GDP.   With annual purchases amounting to twice the deficit, it has become hard to speak of a “market” for government debt. In fact, the BOJ sets the price.

Such a situation can make the central bank hostage to the government’s behavior. The BOJ’s action is predicated on Abe’s commitment to restoring the sustainability of public finances once deflation has been defeated and the economy has returned to growth. Should Abe fail to deliver, the BOJ would be trapped. If it stopped buying government debt, it could trigger a sovereign crisis and reduce the value of its own portfolio.  But continuing its purchases would tighten the government’s grip.

Trust in the government is therefore vital for any central bank that embarks on QE. The EU fiscal framework lacks credibility and does not give the ECB confidence that governments will continue to pursue sustainability after its bond purchases shelter them from market pressure even further.

Moreover, unlike its counterparts, the ECB does not face a single interlocutor. This explains why the ECB, once obsessed with the risk that governments would coalesce to assail its independence, has turned into the staunchest advocate of fiscal-policy coordination.

These concerns do not diminish the need for bold unconventional action against deflation, and it should not prevent the ECB from launching QE. The parallel with Japan highlights the need for governments to behave responsibly, individually and collectively. Europe’s elected national leaders have a large role to play, and they must not eschew their duties. The more confidence they give to the ECB, the more effective QE will be.

To QE or Not?

 

Should the USFed Allow Interest Rates to Normalize?

Jared Meyer writes:  Even though the Federal Reserve has ended its massive bond purchases, interest rates remain near zero, where they have been held since late 2008. Low interest rates remain even though the economy has improved.

The Fed believes that if it can keep long-term interest rates low, business investment and consumer spending will increase and the economy will grow. However, the Federal Reserve is unable to singlehandedly create economic growth. Its role is instead to execute sound, consistent monetary policy, which provides the backdrop for a strong economy.

Historical evidence shows that interest rate increases during the early-to-middle stages of economic expansions do not endanger economic growth. As Boston College economics professor and Shadow Open Market Committee Member Peter Ireland argues,“These higher rates are nothing to be feared. To the contrary, they are a necessary component of a broader policy strategy designed to keep the economy growing along a stable path while maintaining the environment of slow-but-steady inflation that has served the country so well, going back more than a quarter century to the days of Paul Volcker’s Fed chairmanship.”

The Federal Reserve’s continued accommodative monetary policy is unlikely to increase GDP or employment growth. Instead, suppressing interest rates in times of increased and sustained economic growth increases the risk of inflation. It is time for the Federal Reserve to let interest rates rise with the improved economy.

Interest Rates

Entrepreneurial Opportunities in Cuba?

A.. J.  Corchado writes:  When the news of the biggest political thaw in more than half a century between the U.S. and Cuba finally came, Cynthia Thomas discovered an unusual longing.  For more than 14 years, Thomas faced an uphill battle in helping lay the foundation for Texas companies to do business in Cuba. President Barack Obama’s Dec. 17 executive order to normalize relations with Cuba provides Texans with a new opportunity.

While normalization won’t be complete until Congress ends its economic embargo, Thomas and others believe the move is a milestone for the United States, particularly Texas. Over the years, Texas leaders have touted possible deals for beans, cotton, rice, grain, packaged desserts, organic soaps, livestock, even airlines and ports. Success has come slowly, with overall sales of Texas agriculture products topping $89 million in 2009 before falling. Some agricultural products are exempt from the embargo.

The fact that Texas doesn’t carry the political baggage of the swing state of Florida bodes well for the Lone Star State.

Texas and Cuba — the Western Hemisphere’s last communist nation — may seem like an odd match, but they share intriguing bits of history. Both have had revolutions. Both have a passion for gritty cowboys, fine cattle and baseball. And both have unwavering pride in their independent spirit, underscored by their flags, each emblazoned with a single star.  On Fidel Castro’s first and only trip to the United States in 1959, he stopped in Houston, met with a Texas cattlemen’s group and donned a cowboy hat for the cameras.

Texas lore fascinates Cubans. Near Cuba’s heartland town of Camaguey, where Texas’ King Ranch once owned thousands of acres and raised the most prized cattle herd around, locals readily embrace norteño music, known in Texas as Tex-Mex. The properties were expropriated by the Cuban Revolution and are now known as Rancho King, said to be one of Fidel Castro’s favorite places for quiet reflection.

Cuba will require patience for investors and tourists. The island is packed with well-educated residents hungry for technology, new fashion styles, restaurants, etc. Yet much of the population of more than 11 million people is mired in poverty. With a per capita gross domestic product of about $3,900, most Cubans cannot afford pricey foreign products.  The key, he added, will be the development of the Cuban tourism industry, which boasts of its stunning beaches.

 Cuba Opens Up

Why Germany Does Not Lead the EU?

Joachim Gauck, president of Germany, called on Chancellor Merkel to take on global responsibilites. Gauck Speech  This is not Merkel’s style according to a fascinating portrait by George Packer in the New Yorker magazine.

Joachim Fischer, a German social theorist, describes Germany under Merkel as a return to the Biedermeier period between the end of the Napoleanic Wars and the beginning of the 1848 Revoltuions.  The middle class was focused on growing wealth and decorative style.  Peace reigned.  Today the German people overwhelmingly support Merkel.

Stephen Green who wrote “Reluctant Meister: How Germany’s Past is Shapig Europe’s Future” has another thought.  Going back to the revenge of the Romans on Hermann in the 9th century AD and up until the Treaty of Versailles, the German’s could point to their victimhood. This combined with German thinkers emphasis on ‘duty’ which has sometimes been turned to the wrong cause, has wrecked disaster.

Gauck’s criticism of his country’s unwillingness to lead the EU based on its size and economic weight may be apt. But marvel, Green suggests, at the reformed democratic character.

Now the Greek elections which may well be won by Syzria create big problems for Merkel.  Syzria says he will refuse to carry out the austerity measures required for the country’s remaining bail out funds.  He promises to roll back economic reforms also required at the time of the bailout.

Merkel has resisted relenting on austerity.  She has also refused to let the ECB do large scale quantitative easing.  By doing these two things, she may put such a strain on Europe’s currency and demccracy that they being to break apart.  Is this the price of the new democratic Germany led by Merkel?

Hermann

Do Women Prefer Male Bosses?

The higher women climb up the career ladder, the bigger the gender gap grows. Women still hold just 5 percent of CEO positions and 17 percent of board seats, according to research group Catalyst. One of the biggest obstacles to narrowing the gender gap for female leaders may be the employees who work for them.

According to a recent Gallop poll, employees of both genders prefer male bosses to female bosses. Among the 60 percent of employees who have a preference either way, women (40 percent) actually are more likely to prefer a male boss than men (29 percent).

Yet research from leadership consultancy Zenger Folkman shows that women are actually more effective leaders than men, scoring higher on 12 of 16 leadership attributes, according to Robert Sherwin, chief operating officer at Zenger Folkman.

So why don’t we like them more?

Misguided perceptions and stereotypes about female leaders at all levels of the workplace may be playing at play. People believe that women are less effective leaders.  But women score higher than men on developng others, building relationships and collaboration.

Women also scored higher on leadership traits often attributed to men, such as taking initiative, driving results and being a champion for change.

Another reason for the disconnect between the effectiveness of female leaders and the preference for male bosses simply may be that few employees actually know what it’s like to work for a woman.  One of the few subgroups in Gallup’s poll that did not tilt toward a male leader was the 30 percent of employees who work for a female boss. Those employees were equally split in their preferences—perhaps showing that gender equality among leaders creates gender equality among workers as well.

For workers to see the benefits of working for a female boss firsthand, the number of women leaders must increase.  Female role models help inspire women who are aspiring to leadership positions. But they also help educate men who already are in the executive suite about the strength of female leaders and the ways they can improve a company’s performance and results.

The increased adoption of family-friendly workplace polices such as paid maternity and paternity leave also could help drive the growth of female leaders.

Women Bosses Have An Unfair Reputation

US Orders Trade with Asia?

For Michael B. Froman is U.S. trade representative charged with expanding global trade.  He and his colleagues have clocked more than 1,500 meetings on Capitol Hill to promote the president’s big potential trade deal, the Trans-Pacific Partnership.  Its prospects for passage don’t look good.

Some said in the beginning that the deal was too small, with only four Asian countries as members.  Now there are twelve.  Mr. Froman is convinced that he can complete negotiations on a complex trade agreement.

At stake is a colossal trade agreement that would stretch from Peru and Chile to Japan and Vietnam, accounting for 40 percent of the world’s economic activity. It would not just lower tariffs: The pact would require rigorous regulations on labor and environmental standards, as well as the first rules for state-owned enterprises like those run by the governments of Vietnam and Malaysia.

The T.P.P. has emerged as the linchpin of Mr. Obama’s strategic shift to Asia, giving the United States a way to counter the economic inroads made in the region by a rising China. The deal is supposed to be followed by the Trans-Atlantic Trade and Investment Partnership with Europe, though those talks have much farther to go.

Mr. Froman has expressed unwavering confidence in the outcome, saying the various parties are searching for “landing zones” on issues ranging from Japanese farm subsidies to Vietnamese labor regulations..

Democrats may be a big problem.  On the Ways and Means Commitee, members have said they wat to work with the administration on the T.P.P., down to the finest details.

One problem with the Obama administration, made clear in executive orders, is that Mr. Obama is not a talented politician and he prefers ‘orders.’   T.P.P. may have of tough time because of this attitude.

Dean Baker, co-director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research and a consultant to American unions monitoring trade talks, said strong currency provisions would do more to promote middle-class manufacturing jobs than any other provisions, including lowering tariff barriers on American goods.

On the broader concerns of reluctant Democratic senators like Elizabeth Warren of Massachusetts, Mr. Froman pointed to the 18 cases of alleged unfair trade practices the administration has brought before the World Trade Organization, half of them against China, as proof that Mr. Obama can be trusted to watch out for the interests of American workers.

The president has mobilized virtually his entire administration to see the trade agenda through: the Interior Department to work on wildlife trafficking; Health and Human Services to work through pharmaceutical issues, especially intellectual property; the Commerce Department to reach out to businesses; Treasury to handle currency; the Labor Department to address worker rights; the Environmental Protection Agency to deal with land, water and air conservation; and the State Department to take on broader diplomacy. Still you have to ask why the President insists on control.  He is no Lyndon Johnson.

Obama in Control?

 

Young People Can’t Find Jobs

Like many countries around the world, it is the young people, our future, who can’t find jobs in the US.

A Congressional report released Tuesday found that millennials are not feeling the impacts of the economic recovery. Millennials are delaying major life decisions such as buying a home and getting married.
In 2003, nearly 40 percent of Americans between the ages of 25 and 34 headed a household. In 2013, the rate declined to 37.2 percent.

Meanwhile, the percentage of millennials living with their parents has increased from 11 percent before the recession to 14 percent.  Household income adjusted for inflation for Americans aged 25 to 34 declined by more than 10 percent.

While the national unemployment rate remains at 5.8 percent, millennial unemployment is at nearly 17 percent.  American millennials are also more educated than any other previous generation. Sixty-three percent of them have at least some college education. That’s an 11-percentage-point increase from the 52 percent of Americans in that same age bracket who had some level of college education in 1994.

Even if young people land new, better-paying jobs at some point, lower earnings earlier in their careers may result in permanently lower retirement savings and net worth than might have been the case if economic conditions had been better when they first entered the labor force.   Millennials

Young People Jobless