Normal Investors in the Art and Real Estate Markets

On the Rocky Road to Globalization

Kenneth Rogoff writes:  What impact will China’s slowdown have on the red-hot contemporary art market? That might not seem like an obvious question, until one considers that, for emerging-market investors, art has become a critical tool for facilitating capital flight and hiding wealth. These investors have become a major factor in the art market’s spectacular price bubble of the last several years. So, with emerging market economies from Russia to Brazil mired in recession, will the bubble burst?

Just five months ago, Larry Fink, Chairman and CEO of BlackRock, the world’s largest asset manager, said that contemporary art has become one of the two most important stores of wealth internationally, along with apartments in major cities such as New York, London, and Vancouver. Forget gold as an inflation hedge; buy paintings.

Pablo Picasso’s “Women of Algiers” sold for $179 million at a Christie’s auction in New York, up from $32 million in 1997. Okay, it’s a Picasso. Yet it is not even the highest sale price paid this year. A Swiss collector reportedly paid close to $300 million in a private sale for Paul Gauguin’s 1892 “When Will You Marry?”

For economists, the art bubble raises many fascinating questions.  Art is the last great unregulated investment opportunity.

Doesn’t China have a regime of strict capital controls that limits citizens from taking more than $50,000 per year out of the country? Yes, but there are many ways of moving money in and out of China, including the time-honored method of “under and over invoicing.” Many estimates put capital flight from China at about $300 billion annually in recent years.

For example, to get money out of China, a Chinese seller might report a dollar value far below what she was actually paid by a cooperating Western importer, with the difference being deposited into an overseas bank account. It is extremely difficult to estimate capital flight. Identifying capital flight is akin to the old adage about blind men touching an elephant: It is difficult to describe, but you will recognize it when you see it.

The art may well be spirited off to a temperature- and humidity-controlled storage vault in Switzerland or Luxembourg. Reportedly, some art sales today result in paintings merely being moved from one section of a storage vault to another, recalling how the New York Federal Reserve registers gold sales between national central banks.

So how, then, will the emerging-market slowdown radiating from China affect contemporary art prices? In the short run, the answer is ambiguous, because more money is leaking out of the country even as the economy slows. In the long run, the outcome is pretty clear, especially if one throws in the coming Fed interest-rate hikes. With core buyers pulling back, and the opportunity cost rising, the end of the art bubble will not be a pretty picture.

Capital Flight

The Economics of Aging

The economics of long lives

Gerardo P. Sicat writes: My comments are occasioned by the passing away of my mother-in-law last Saturday, at the age of 102 years and eight months. My own mother, who passed away a few years back, had lived up to the ripe age of 96 years.

Both mothers were born in the decade of the 1910s when life expectancy at birth was likely well below 60 years. Then, antibiotics and public health standards were very low and incomes and facilities also much worse.

Long lives. Barring the occurrence of accidents, catastrophes, wars and other life-shortening natural events , the economic and social milieus in which we live, in addition to one’s genes, have much to do on how long one eventually lives.

The improvement of incomes (through economic development and growth) help to lengthen lives, for this affords the individual better nutrition, infrastructure (social, physical and economic), and improved leisure and comfort.

At the other end, developments in the medical sciences and the advancement of public sanitation have life-extending influences on everyone.

The economics of life. Economists have advanced the proposition that in general, people balance the incomes they earn against their total expenditures in their lifetime. However, during specific stages of their lives, the patterns of income and expenditure differ.

 

In the last stage of life, that income earning capacity declines and eventually stops. As one lives beyond those productive years, the net earnings beyond the expenses of the past (which are savings) represent the sustenance that tide us over to the end of life.

Development and the improvement of social networks. The network of support for old age in traditional societies is often the family or the clan. As productive life ends and infirmities develop, the family becomes the principal support for their old folks.

With economic development, society through government, finds ways of extending social support networks to supplement the role of the family.

The most important feature of such social support networks are social security and universal medical insurance. Social security is paid for by taxation of individuals, otherwise, it becomes unsustainable for a society to bear.

Universal medical insurance is often undertaken through the insurance principle of actuarial equivalence. In this setup, the premiums collected are calculated to match the benefits received.

Government-sponsored social support networks affect the life cycle income. They help to augment the capacity to generate savings for the individual. For instance, social security contributions can raise the saving process. As a result, they enlarge the stream of pension incomes in the post-retirement stage.

In the Philippines,the social security fund thus generated can only provide a stream low pension payments.

The average pensioner in the Philippines receives less pension incomes compared to the “miracle” economies in East Asia.  Her husband was hardworking, competent and brilliant. He would become the chief magistrate of the land. He had also taught law for years to supplement his government pay. After the husband died, she continued to receive his social security pension.

Two decades later, as if by an act of God, legislation granting pensions for survivors of members of the judiciary. For my mother-in-law, this changed the situation very much. The cost of senior sustenance was more than adequately covered. However, when her final illnesses worsened and her medical condition became serious, that pension and previous savings from it were easily and totally consumed.

My mother’s case was uniquely different from my mother-in-law’s. From the beginning, she was the traditional housewife. Her life’s income was integrated with that of my father who was a small proprietorial businessman.

When my father died,  my mother continued the business. But she had no no social security pension like most small businessmen. She survived on what little remained.

During the 1970s, my mother migrated to the US where she joined my sisters who had migrated right after John F. Kennedy’s immigration liberalization.

In the US, my mother was very useful although she did not secure formal employment. As an elderly person, she received some welfare benefits from the State where she lived enabling her to sustain her own upkeep in old age even as she lived with her children.

 Bad Boss Pic 5

Does the EU Need a Circular Economy?

EU’s circular economy can help the union thrive.

Europe’s economy has generated unprecedented wealth over the past century. Part of the success is attributable to continuous improvements in resource productivity—a trend that has started to reduce Europe’s resource exposure. At the same time, resource productivity remains hugely underexploited as a source of wealth, competitiveness, and renewal. Our new study, Growth within: A circular economy vision for a competitive Europe,1 provides new evidence that a circular economy, enabled by the technology revolution, would allow Europe to grow resource productivity by up to 3 percent annually. This would generate a primary-resource benefit of as much as €0.6 trillion per year by 2030 to Europe’s economies. In addition, it would generate €1.2 trillion in nonresource and externality benefits, bringing the annual total benefits to around €1.8 trillion compared with today.

This would translate into a GDP increase of as much as seven percentage points relative to the current development scenario, with an additional positive impact on employment. Looking at the systems for three human needs (mobility, food, and the built environment), our study concludes that rapid technology adoption is necessary but not sufficient to capture the circular opportunity. Instead, circular principles must guide the transition differently from those that govern today’s economy. Pursued consistently, the economic promise is significant and the circular economy could qualify as the next major European political-economy project.

Europe’s economy remains very resource dependent. Views differ on how to address this against an economic backdrop of low and jobless growth as well as the struggle to reinvigorate competitiveness and absorb massive technological change.

Proponents of a circular economy argue that it offers Europe a major opportunity to increase resource productivity, decrease resource dependence and waste, and increase employment and growth. They maintain that a circular system would improve competitiveness and unleash innovation, and they see abundant circular opportunities that are inherently profitable but remain uncaptured.  Towards a Circular Economy

Solar Power Up in Hawaii. Pricing Bias?

Brittany Lyle writes:  Hawaii’s electricity prices are higher than anywhere else in the nation. The burdensome cost of power, paired with the island state’s plentiful sunshine, has led to an unparalleled adoption of residential rooftop solar energy. On the island of Oahu, where 80 percent of the state’s population lives, more than 12 percent of Hawaiian Electric Co. (HECO) customers have rooftop solar systems — about 20 times the solar penetration rate of any mainland utility. As homes increasingly morph into mini power plants, some residents are winding down their HECO bills to net zero.

The problem is this: When solar customers provide their own power, they don’t pay for the fixed costs the utility has outside of electricity generation. As more and more people switch to solar, an ever-shrinking pool of utility customers still connected to the grid are left to cover these operating and maintenance expenses. This causes bills to spike for traditional customers, which incentivizes even more people to switch to solar, raising bills for nonsolar customers even more. Every new rooftop solar installation added to the grid contributes to this cost shift.

‘It could be that all of the people living in apartments are going to be subsidizing the millionaires with their huge estates covered in rooftop solar. I don’t think we’re quite at that point yet, but we need to change or that’s where we’re headed.’
Oahu’s solar energy boom is unleashing what’s known in the industry as the utility death spiral. The prediction is that it will overwhelmingly hurt the most vulnerable people — namely those without control over their roof space, such as renters and apartment and condominium owners, as well as low- and moderate-income homeowners who can’t afford the high up-front cost of a rooftop solar installation.

“It could be that all of the people living in apartments are going to be subsidizing the millionaires with their huge estates covered in rooftop solar,” said Michael Roberts, an economics professor who studies electricity pricing at the University of Hawaii at Manoa. “I don’t think we’re quite at that point yet, but we need to change or that’s where we’re headed.”

In 2014, HECO’s nonsolar customers picked up the tab for an extra $53 million in operating and maintenance costs because so many people switched to solar. It is estimated that they will pay an additional $80 million in 2015.

As the island grapples with the task of making a biased energy pricing system more equitable, mainland utilities with large and growing solar energy bases in states like California, Arizona, New Jersey and Colorado are looking at Oahu and watching their future unfold.

In the basement of the faded 1934 cottage where he was raised, Kong thumbed through a filing cabinet in search of his utility bill records. Vintage Hawaiian slack key guitar music buzzed on an old radio. A small electric fan circulated warm air in the room.

A retired Pearl Harbor security guard, Kong inherited his childhood home. But he lives next door in a newer, five-bedroom house that he shares with his wife, two daughters, son-in-law, grandson and the occasional foreign exchange student. The house stands on a corner lot in Honolulu’s Kaimuki section, once an ostrich farm owned by the Kingdom of Hawaii’s royal doctor. Bordering the iconic Diamond Head volcano, it is one of the city’s oldest neighborhoods.

He pulled from his files his HECO bill from February. In time with the music, he tapped a finger next to the figure for the total due: $336. That’s a 53 percent increase from his bill for the same month two years earlier.

“I think about shutting the power down, putting the two refrigerators on a generator and using flashlight and candles,” Kong said. “If it wasn’t for the refrigerators, I’d shut the power off now when we go to sleep.”

solar panels, hawaii

 

China Begs to Enter the World. And Does.

Bloomberg writes:  For years, China’s leaders have wanted the world to acknowledge their economy’s leading role in the global system. This week they got their wish. Sadly, the circumstances weren’t ideal.

The crash in global stock markets began with gloom about China’s prospects and muddle over what the authorities in Beijing intend. Global markets may be calming down, but the confusion hasn’t gone away. The Chinese government and its critics all need to think a bit more clearly about what is going on.

In the past few days, China has been a whipping boy for everyone from Japan’s finance minister to U.S. Republican presidential hopefuls.  Its central bank is accused of waging a currency war with its devaluation of the yuan two weeks ago. Before that, critics chided Chinese authorities for perpetuating a stock-market bubble by intervening extensively in equities; this week’s sell-off accelerated when the government declined to prop them up.

The world doesn’t seem quite sure what it wants from China’s leaders. Critics scold Beijing for boosting stocks, then panic when they don’t. They insist market forces be allowed to set the yuan, then howl when those forces push it down. They tell China to accept slower growth as the price of rebalancing its economy, then clamor then for stimulus when the economy slows.

To be sure, there’s confusion in Beijing as well. Leaders have promised to shift the economy onto a more sustainable growth path that’s based less on exports and more on services and domestic demand. But they’ve held to an unreasonably high growth target.

There’s an underlying tension in that mix: The leadership is sincere about its desire for markets to allocate capital more efficiently, yet mostly in order to preserve the power and position of the Communist Party. Party needs come first.

Beijing’s reluctance to surrender more fully to market discipline is understandable given the daunting list of challenges leaders face. But they’re only storing up problems for the future.

The government is paying the price now for having artificially boosted stocks earlier. The central bank is thought to be spending an estimated $40 billion a month to keep the yuan from falling further and prevent capital flight. Authorities are reportedly considering raising an additional $161 billion in bonds to fund new infrastructure projects. Some of these may make good sense, but the fact that Beijing is directing the program raises doubts..

More forthrightness now would buy China goodwill from markets when the government really does need to intervene — as the U.S., Japan and the European Union have all repeatedly judged to be necessary. Chinese leaders should remember that the currency that matters most is their credibility.

China enters the world

 

How Bad is Unemployment in China?

According to official statistics, China’s unemployment rate has remained at an exceptionally steady 4.0-4.3% since 2002, despite massive change in the economy over that period. A new National Bureau of Economic Research paper analyzing national household survey data from 1988-2009 suggests that the official index may have significantly underestimated the actual urban unemployment rate.  

From the abstract:  The rate averaged 3.9% in 1988-1995, when the labor market was highly regulated and dominated by state-owned enterprises, but rose sharply during the period of mass layoff from 1995- 2002, reaching an average of 10.9% in the subperiod from 2002 to 2009.

The survey does not cover more recent data, so their research does not show whether the labor market has deteriorated as the Chinese economy has slowed. But their figures do point to the large, lasting impact of the mass closures of bankrupt state-owned companies in the 1990s. The unemployment rate was just 3.9% from 1988-95 and then climbed steadily upwards. State firms had played the biggest role in China’s north-east and so their closures dealt the region a particularly heavy blow, with its unemployment rate averaging 12.5% from 2002-9.

Just how worrying are these findings? The data comes from the urban household survey, which is conducted by the National Bureau of Statistics.  Their unemployment index is more volatile than the registered jobless rate, making for a closer fit to the ebb and flow of economic cycles in China.

But if the official rock-steady 4.1% jobless rate is trusted by no one, the conclusion that China suffers from chronic unemployment of more than 10% is also worthy of a large dose of skepticism. As the authors readily admit, there is a major gap in their data. The survey only covers people who hold local hukou, or residency permits, and therefore excludes the tens of millions of migrants who stream to cities for work every year. In Shanghai, for example, some 14m residents hold local hukou, but another 10m people live and work in the city on a permanent basis. The latter are outside the remit of the urban household survey.

There is also good reason to think that the 10.9% unemployment rate exaggerates the problem.

The dataset doesn’t reflect rural migrant workers, even though they have been a huge source of urban labor in the last decade, making up as much as half of China’s urban workforce today.  That could mean that the actual unemployment rate is lower.   On the other hand, nearly 60% of rural migrant workers work in construction and manufacturing (link in Chinese). Given China’s slowing economy and sluggish export demand, they might soon be pushing the true unemployment rate up. 

Reporting on the new unemployment index for CBS Moneywatch, Robert Hanley notes that China’s economic slowdown has been apparent in the rising instances of labor unrest in recent years:

"Maybe unemployment is worse than I thought"

“Maybe unemployment is worse than I thought

Is the Greek Bailout Deal a One-Night Stand?

Wolfgang Streeck writes:  Now the dust has temporarily settled over the ruins of Greece’s economy, it is worth asking if there wasn’t a brief moment when the actors had found a way to cut the eurozone crisis’s Gordian knot. At some point in July German finance minister, Wolfgang Schäuble, appeared to have realized that his dream of a “core Europe” with a Franco-German avant-garde would vanish into thin air if Greece was allowed to remain in the economic and monetary union. Rewriting the rules of the union to accommodate the Greeks, Schäuble realised, would pull the euro southwards, and France, Italy and Spain with it – forever breaking up the European core.

His Greek equivalent Yanis Varoufakis, for his part, may have learned from his encounters of the third kind with the Eurogroup that the only role there was for Greece in the Europe of monetary union was that of an underfed and overregulated welfare recipient. Not only was this incompatible with Greek national pride; more importantly, what the governors of Europe would be willing to offer the Greeks by way of “European solidarity” would, at best, be too little to live on,   The deal Schäuble offered in the last hour of July’s battle of the euro might have been worth exploring: a voluntary exit (an involuntary one not being possible under the current treaties) that gave Greece the freedom to devalue its currency and return to an independent monetary and fiscal policy, plus emergency assistance and some restructuring of the national debt, outside of the monetary union to avoid softening its rules by creating a precedent. A generous golden handshake might have also been an idea, protecting Germany from being blamed for having plunged the Greeks into misery or driven them into the arms of Vladimir Putin.   Future of Eurozone

Is the Greek Bailout Deal a One-Night Stand?

End Ban on Oil Exports in the US?

The Rocky Road to Globalization

The Economist reports:  When  the economics textbooks of the future are written, America’s ban on crude-oil exports will be a fine example of the perverse effects of protectionism. Similarly, a new decision by Barack Obama’s administration to allow American firms to sell some oil to Mexico will earn an honorable footnote in the story of the ban’s demise.

Geology, engineering, economics and politics are all at stake. In the fuel-hungry 1970s, America banned crude-oil exports in an effort to stabilize domestic prices. The country’s oil refineries are still configured to deal with the heavy, sour crude oil it used to import. Now, thanks to the shale revolution, American oil imports have plunged just as production has soared. Oil from shale is another kind of crude, light and sweet. It is not ideal for America’s refineries, which must make costly tweaks to deal with it. But the ban means this oil can’t be exported, either.

That archaic rule now keeps the price of America’s domestically produced oil, signalled by the West Texas Intermediate (WTI) benchmark, at a hefty discount—currently over $5 per barrel—to the world price. That has become particularly painful since OPEC’s decision in November to stop trying to curb production, which has sent prices tumbling. American oilmen are fuming: their potential export markets are being sacrificed, they argue, to the interests of America’s petrochemical industry, which enjoys artificially cheap feedstock thanks to the ban.

Others would benefit too.  Free trade in crude would boost American output, investment, jobs, pay, profits and tax revenues—and GDP by $86 billion.  With American crude bringing prices down, most likely the cost of fuel would fall a bit—for Americans, and also for other consumers.

The administration’s decision will test this theory. Mexico’s national oil company, Pemex, has long wanted to send its heavy crude to America, and import the same number of barrels of lighter American oil.  The Commerce Department has now decided to treat Mexico as part of the domestic American market, as far as oil is concerned.

The extent of the exemption is still unclear. But this is not the first breach of the ban. The definition of what constitutes crude oil owes more to art (and bureaucratic fiat) than science. What is heavy crude?  What is light?

The ban undermines America’s moral authority at the World Trade Organisation, where the administration has berated China, for example, for imposing export bans on scarce minerals. Higher American crude-oil exports would also hurt petrostates such as Russia and Iran.

The details will still be tricky. America’s cossetted crude-oil consumers would be willing to see an end to artificially cheap raw materials in exchange for other concessions. These could include laxer environmental rules, or a change in an even more archaic law, the Jones Act, which bans foreign ships from carrying cargo between American ports. This law delights ship-owners and unions, but imposes a hefty cost on anyone wanting to send a tanker from, say, a refinery on the Gulf coast to a port in the north-east.

Such a wholesale solution to this elderly quirk in the world oil market may still be some time off. But by lowering trade barriers for Mexican oil, the Obama administration will make America richer, improve the functioning of the world oil market and highlight the potential benefits of still more dramatic reforms. 

Oil Exports and Price

Bring US Corporate Taxes in Conformity with the World’s?

The Rocky Road to Globalization

President Barack Obama said last September that he would get tough on companies that avoid tax through “inversions”—merging with or buying foreign firms so as to shift their domicile abroad—some wondered if this would end a wave of corporate emigration. Some high-profile deals were called off, but other companies have continued to tiptoe out of America to places where the taxman is kinder and has shorter arms.

For many firms, staying in America is just too costly. Take Burger King, a fast-food chain, which last year shifted domicile to Canada after merging with Tim Horton’s, a coffee-shop operator there. Before the move, it would have had to pay up to 39% tax on foreign earnings when it brought them into America. Now that it is Canadian, it pays 39% only on profits earned in America, about 26% on Canadian profits and the (often lower) local rate elsewhere.

Inversions can cause a domino effect within industries, as the first companies to emigrate to a low-tax country gain an advantage that prompts rivals to follow suit. The logical way to stem the tide would be to bring America’s tax laws in line with international norms. Britain, Germany and Japan all have lower corporate rates and are among the majority of countries that tax firms only on profits earned on their territory. But the likelihood of a substantial tax reform in America is low—vanishingly so before 2017.

So, rather than making it nicer for companies to stay, the US Treasury has been trying to make it harder for them to leave. There has long been a rule whereby any inversion resulting in the American firm’s shareholders owning 80% of the merged group would be taxed as if it were still American. In September, loopholes in this rule were closed

AbbVie, a drug company, blamed these stricter rules when it abandoned plans to merge with Shire of Ireland. Walgreens, a pharmacy chain, insisted it also had other reasons for dropping a plan to move to Europe, though its patriotic decision to stay American earned it some good publicity.

Despite such speed bumps, inversions still make enormous sense for companies with large overseas operations. If anything, the rule changes have led to more companies looking to get out before it is too late.

Emigrating from Deerfield, Illinois to London, as in CF Industries’ case, or from Minnesota to Dublin, as in Medtronic’s, isn’t as dramatic as it seems. These tend to be mainly paper moves. “Here in the Netherlands you don’t even need a chimney to be domiciled,” says Indra Romgens, a corporate researcher, of the country’s many brass-plate headquarters. But the tides are slowly turning, as low-tax countries are beginning to require relocating companies to have a more substantial presence.

Now stricter anti-inversion rules make it harder for American firms to pursue de facto takeovers of foreign rivals, they are becoming the prey rather than the predators. If the American authorities succeeded in stopping inversions, all that would happen is that foreign takeovers of American firms would accelerate.

US Corporate Taxes

 

IMF Chief Lagarde: Greek Deal Good, but…

IMF chief Christine Lagarde on Friday welcomed Europe’s decision to agree a new 86-billion-euro bailout for Greece, but warned that Athens’ debt is still too high.

“I remain firmly of the view that Greece’s debt has become unsustainable and that Greece cannot restore debt sustainability solely through actions on its own,” she said.

And, while Lagarde called the agreement hammered out in Brussels “a very important step forward,” she warned it was too soon to say whether the IMF would provide funds to take part in the bailout.

“We look forward to working closely with Greece and its European partners in the coming months to put in place all the elements needed for me to recommend to the fund’s executive board to consider further financial support for Greece,” she said.

For this to be the case, she said, Greece’s European creditors would themselves have to provide “significant debt relief, well beyond what has been considered so far.”

Greek Debt